Getting rid of a unit of currency is a step usually only taken in extreme circumstances or after long, careful planning — Zimbabwe’s battle with hyperinflation is an example of the former, the transition to the euro the latter.
India’s recent experiment with demonetisation was something altogether different.
At 8pm on November 8 2016, without any prior warning or expectation, prime minister Narendra Modi dramatically announced that all 500 and 1000 rupee banknotes would be invalid after midnight – just four hours after the announcement. These were the two highest value notes and accounted for 86% of all the cash in the Indian economy. The notes would be replaced by new 500 and 2000 rupee notes, Modi said, and the public would have a few months to exchange their now defunct currency in banks, albeit only in small allotments.
So began the saga of India’s “2016 demonetisation” – a move now almost universally considered woefully short-sighted and high-handed.
One of the main aims of the policy, according to the government, was to curb the influence of “black money” in the shadow economy and stop wealthy Indians evading taxes. It was a classic political tactic – convincing large sections of the working class who were facing most of the inconveniences that the “rich” were the ones being punished.
But the idea that black money is still predominantly stored in the form of cash in lockers and suitcases under beds is totally outdated. In fact, income tax investigations have shown that cash made up only about 6 per cent of undeclared wealth in the country, and wealthy tax evaders have access to a variety of ways to convert this cash – for example, demand for gold surged immediately after the announcement.
Basic research in psychology and economics should also have given ample warning that clever market mechanisms would be sure to pop up to facilitate the deposition of as much black money as possible, especially in a country with inefficient monitoring and prosecution of crimes like money laundering. One example was that a market appeared for people to sell their old notes at a discount – and the buyers would then distribute these notes out across a network of people to deposit in small amounts to avoid raising suspicion.
What’s more, there is a distinction to be made between black money and money made in the informal economy – the former stems from tax evasion, mostly by the rich, while the latter arises organically in countries without state institutions capable of monitoring small and medium-sized enterprises.
Ninety per cent of Indian workers make their living in this informal sector, and 78 per cent of all transactions occur in cash. In rural areas, people seldom have bank accounts, let alone carry out transactions in anything but cash. People’s savings in these parts of the country are also quite often in cash.
Modi’s sudden demonetisation forced millions of poor people to spend time they would have been working queuing at banks to deposit and exchange notes, an imposition which was particularly harmful for daily wage labourers. To make matters worse, the daily limit on exchange and deposits prolonged the painful process over weeks.
By August of last year, 99 per cent of the demonetised notes had been deposited to the banks, a much larger percentage than the government expected – leading to a general consensus that the policy had not affected black money significantly after all. And the idea that removing big denominations would stop people hoarding cash was undermined by the introduction of an even larger denomination, the 2000 rupee note – ultimately the policy has only made it easier for tax evaders to convert black money into white.
The government also claimed the policy was part of a move towards a cashless economy – or at least one that relies less on cash. While there was an immediate spike in digital transactions following the announcement (the public had very few other options), the rate soon fell back to its usual level of growth – hardly the kind of transformation that warranted banning 86 per cent of available currency.
To compound matters, there was also a 1 per cent fall in the expected GDP growth rate in the first quarter following the policy – down to 6.1 per cent against a forecast of 7.1 per cent. In fact it has taken until the first quarter of 2018 to reach 7.1 per cent. There was also fall in industrial output and employment rates, especially in the informal sector, with over 1.5 million jobs lost in the first quarter on 2017.
While the move did have some positive consequences, such as a reduction in human trafficking and greater rates of income tax filing and local tax payments, the effects have widely been understood to be purely ones of shock value, rather than the kind of systemic change Modi envisaged.
For all these failings, the government did still have cause to be smug – while garnering almost unanimous criticism from all reputable experts, demonetisation was popular with large swathes of the population, which was reflected in the results of midterm regional elections that followed soon after. Various sections of the public, while facing only negative effects themselves, felt like they were giving up little in order to be part of a larger movement to get back at the “rich” – even if in reality wealthy Indians suffered little from the policy.
Every single problem the government claimed to be addressing with the silver bullet of demonetisation would be better tackled with the hard graft of institutional change – whether that is in re-evaluating tax policy and making sure it is implemented better, promoting digital transaction mechanisms, or strengthening legal institutions in order to discourage laundering or illegal activity.
Demonetisation was at best a half-baked policy with little evidence or theory to back it and a complete disservice to the Indian people. At worst – and probably more likely – it was simply a cynical, populist ploy to shore up support for Modi’s government.